How Mainstream Economics Failed To Grasp The Importance Of Inequality
The restricted focus of mainstream
economists has meant that not much attention has been given to the
economic and social consequences of changing income and wealth
inequality. Jon D. Wisman critiques
their restricted scope and contends that it impeded them from seeing
how 30 years of wage stagnation and soaring inequality were generating
excessive speculation, indebtedness, and political changes that set the
underlying conditions for the financial crisis of 2008.
The financial crisis of 2008 launched
the second most severe depression in capitalism’s history. Although its
causes have been endlessly discussed, attention has remained fixed on
surface reality or proximate causes such deregulation, inadequate
oversight, low interest rates, “irrational exuberance,” and moral
hazard. Ignored has been what was going on beneath the surface: 30 years
of wage stagnation and exploding inequality—powerful forces that were
churning up complex dynamics to make a financial crisis all but
inevitable. During the 1920s, the same forces had set the stage for the
crash of 1929, but the economics profession missed that one too.
The magnitude of exploding inequality since the mid-1970s is captured by the following: Between 1979 and 2007, inflation-adjusted income,
including capital gains, increased $4.8 trillion — about $16,000 per
person. Of this, 36 percent was captured by the richest 1 percent of
income earners, representing a 232 percent increase in their per capita
income. The richest 10 percent captured 64 percent, almost twice the
amount collected by the 90 percent below. Between 1983 and 2007, total
inflation-adjusted wealth in the U.S. increased by $27 trillion.
If divided equally, every man woman and child would be almost $90,000
richer. But of course it wasn’t divided equally. Almost half of the $27
trillion (49 percent) was claimed by the richest one percent — $11.7
million more for each of their households. The top 10 percent grabbed almost $29 trillion,
or 106 percent, more than the total because the bottom 90 percent
suffered an average decline of just over $16,000 per household as their
indebtedness increased.
This soaring inequality generated three
dynamics that set the conditions for a financial crisis. The first
resulted from limited investment potential in the real economy due to
weak consumer demand as those who consume most or all their incomes
received proportionately much less. Not being capable of spending all
their increased income and wealth, the elite sought profitable
investments increasingly in financial markets, fueling first a stock
market boom, and then after the high tech bubble burst in 2001, a real
estate boom.
As financial markets were flooded with
credit, the profits and size of the financial sector exploded, helping
keep interest rates low and encouraging the creation of new high-risk
credit instruments. This enabled more of the elite’s increased income
and wealth to be recycled as loans to workers. Financial institutions
were so flush with funds that they undertook ever more risky loans, the
most infamous being the predatory subprime mortgages that often were racially targeted.
As the elite became ever richer, those below became ever more indebted
to them. When this debt burden became unsustainable, the financial
system collapsed and was bailed out by taxpayers.
The second dynamic resulting from wage
stagnation and soaring inequality is that as the elite with ever more
income and wealth ratcheted up their consumption on luxury goods in
competition among themselves for the pinnacle of status, everyone below
was pressured to consume more both to meet family needs and to maintain
their relative status or social respectability. In effect, the elite’s
dramatically larger shares of income and wealth led to a “consumption arms race.” Pressure
was especially strong in housing, the most important asset and symbol
of social status for most Americans. As a consequence, over the three
decades building up to the crisis, the household saving rate plummeted
from 10 percent of disposable income in the early 1980s to near zero by
2006, as Figure 1 illustrates. By 2007, the average married household
worked 19 percent more
hours than they did in 1979—the equivalent of over one extra work day
per week, or an extra 14 work weeks per year—and household debt as a
percent of disposable income doubled from about 62 percent in 1974 to
129 percent in late 2007.
Figure 1 – Personal savings rate 1980 – 2010
Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis National Income and Product Accounts 2012, Section 7.
The third dynamic is that as the rich
took an ever-greater share of income and wealth, they and their
corporate interests gained greater command over politics and ideology so
as to further change the rules of the game in their favor. The
proliferation of right-wing think tanks, corporate lobbyists and
corporate campaign contributions leveraged their political influence. In
their competition for status among themselves, they understandably
supported self-interested economic and political measures that brought
them yet greater shares of the nation’s income and wealth.
As the elite’s command over essentially
everything grew, so too did their ability to craft self-serving
ideology—especially supply-side economics, a variant of laissez faire
economics—in a manner that made it be ever-more convincing to a majority of the electorate.
Flowing out of this ideology were tax cuts favoring the wealthy, a
weakened safety net for the least fortunate, budget cuts for public
services, freer trade, weaken unions, deregulation of the economy
(especially the financial sector), and the failure to regulate newly
evolving credit instruments.
How did the mainstream of economists not
see the unstable financial conditions that soaring inequality was
creating? Generally because economists have not viewed the distribution
of income and wealth as an important domain of study. The 1995 recipient
of the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences even went so far as
to declare that “Of
the tendencies that are harmful to sound economics, the most seductive,
and in my opinion the most poisonous, is to focus on questions of
distribution.” Moreover, rising inequality has long been dismissed by
economists as either irrelevant (if everyone is becoming materially
better off, the size of shares is unimportant) or as missing the
economic dynamism that inequality generates (which in fact it does not!!).
Mainstream economists were also blinded
to the dynamics greater inequality set in motion by their tendency to
focus narrowly on market phenomena, their refusal to study the manner in
which humans as social beings react to the behavior of others, and
their failure to address the nexus between economic and political power.
Economists might have stood a better
chance of foreseeing the developing financial crisis had they thrown
their nets far wider to catch the insights that have been harvested by a
wide range of so-called heterodox economists. From the
underconsumptionist tradition of Keynes, Kalecki, and Minsky they could
have developed an understanding of how inequality affects aggregate
demand, investment, and financial stability. From the institutionalist
tradition of Thorstein Veblen they could have learned how consumption
preferences are socially formed by humans who are as concerned with
social status and respectability as with material well-being. And from
the Marxist tradition they could have seen how economic power translates
into political power. Economists have failed to grasp the wisdom of one of the foremost students of crises:
“the economist who resorts to only one model is stunted. Economics is a
toolbox from which the economist should select the appropriate tool or
model for a particular problem.”
This article has been drawn from the paper “Wage Stagnation, Rising Inequality, and the Financial Crisis of 2008,” which was published in the Cambridge Journal of Economics. It was first published by USAPP@LSE.
No comments:
Post a Comment