Germany’s first post-war Chancellor Konrad Adenauer is usually held to be the origin of an often-quoted phrase „Was kümmert mich mein Geschwätz von gestern?“.
Roughly: why should I be concerned about the rubbish I talked
yesterday? Whatever the rights and wrongs of this attribution, the
phrase – used to draw attention to someone who places political
flexibility over intellectual consistency – has occurred to me numerous
times over recent months in the context of Germany’s debate over the
introduction of a statutory minimum wage.
The statutory minimum wage in Germany
The decision was finally taken yesterday in the Bundestag.
Germany will, for the first time in its history, apply a statutory
minimum wage of EUR 8.50 to almost all workers from the start of 2015.
It is estimated that up to 3.7 million workers will benefit, and given
very pronounced wage inequality at the bottom of the German labour
market, the wage rises for some workers will be substantial.
There is a two-year transition phase for pre-existing sectoral
collective agreements. A number of groups of workers have been excluded,
some permanently the majority for a transition period, from the minimum
wage requirement, which has given rise to an intense debate in the
country.
This debate about
exemptions, as with the battle over the minimum wage more generally, has
centred, unsurprisingly, on possible negative employment effects. Once
the minimum wage has been introduced it will be possible to analyse its
employment effects, even if this will be difficult because its impact
will not be easy to disentangle from that of other factors happening at
the same time. For the moment, one has to rely on studies focusing on
past minimum wage introductions and increases in other countries. The
thrust of that literature is that, provided the minimum wage is at a
“reasonable rate”, it is very hard to identify negative employment
effects in the aggregate. (For a discussion of whether EUR 8.50 is
“reasonable” in the German context see here.)
What
we will see though is a lot of “argument by anecdote”. Firm A in region
B has been forced into bankruptcy by wage increases necessitated by the
minimum wage. Worker C in city D was happy about the minimum wage when
it was being discussed, but now he is furious because instead of a job
paying EUR 6.50 he is unemployed. Indeed, we are already seeing this
argument being deployed in the form of threats and predictions. Handelsblatt, the German business daily, recently had a piece whose title asks whether the minimum wage will lead to bankruptcies (“Pleiten dank Mindestlohn?”, Handelsblatt,
15.05.14). The article answers the rhetorical question in the
affirmative, based on the opinions of the director of the hotel and
catering lobby organisation, the board chairman of a chain of
hairdressers, and the president of the German employers association BDA.
And this concern has been expressed by many liberal economists, by
employer-linked think tanks such as the Initiative Neue Soziale Marktwirtschaft[1], and, not least, by the German Council of Economic Advisers.[2]
Political flexibility or intellectual consistency?
What
I find interesting here is less the specific arguments put forward
(which are rather weak) than the fact that the basis for the arguments
is completely at odds with the way that employers’ representatives[3],
and certainly liberal economists, normally position themselves. It is as
if, on the issue of the minimum wage they are collectively saying: why
should I be concerned about the rubbish I talked yesterday?
Consider
the debate on free trade. A country has tariffs that protect a sector
of its economy. They are removed, leading to job losses and bankruptcies
in the least productive firms in that sector. Do employer
representatives and liberal economists favour an anecdotal approach here
and call for the reimposition of tariffs in order to protect jobs and
companies? On the whole they take a very different line. The production
and employment protected by the tariffs is “inefficient”. Free trade
brings a welcome does of competition. It enables higher incomes and a
shift of production to areas in which the country has a comparative
advantage. Workers who lose their jobs move to more productive
occupations or regions and everyone is better off. (At least, the more
sophisticated would add, this is the case after an intervening
adjustment period.) Focusing on protecting “old” jobs is a barrier to
productivity and progress. One cannot judge from individual job losses
that the overall employment level must fall.
A
similar argument is put forward with respect to technological change.
Yes, some workers are thrown out of work when new, more efficient
machinery and production processes are introduced. Others have to adjust
through training. But here, too, the overall impact is beneficial
(after a lag), because lost employment can be recouped elsewhere in the
economy, as higher-productivity jobs pay higher wages that in turn
expand employment opportunities for workers in other parts of the
economy. If you are against technological change you are a Luddite and
economically illiterate.
This begs
the question why different standards seemingly apply in the case of the
minimum wage. Firms facing a rise in labour costs in the wake of its
introduction have a number of ways to adjust. (These are not mutually
exclusive in practice but can be separated for expositional purposes.)
They can increase prices. Given that the minimum wage applies across the
whole economy (i.e. will not just affect individual firms) this is
likely to happen. Relative prices will adjust: the prices of goods and
services produced with the use of large quantities of low-skilled labour
will increase relative to those using more high-skill labour and
capital. The economic (not technical) productivity of the low-wage
workers will rise, thanks to higher product and service prices, to match
the increase in their wages. Or firms can raise their productivity (in
the technical sense), through innovation and reorganisation, just like a
firm facing a dose of wholesome foreign competition because tariffs
have been cut. Companies may also accept a lower profitability, and the
wage share would rise somewhat. (If nothing else, this would make Thomas
Picketty happy).
But, undoubtedly,
in some firms these adjustment strategies may not be practicable or
sufficient. Some may lay off workers and others be forced to close. This
is the basis for the anecdotal argument. But surely, given their normal
argumentative pattern, business representatives and liberal economists
should be vociferously pointing out that this is actually not a problem,
certainly not an inevitable one. For as we have seen a minimum wage has
very similar effects to a bracing dose of foreign competition or the
“creative destruction” associated with technology. Induced productivity
gains and higher wages generate additional income that sustains
employment in firms across the whole economy. Those employers that
cannot keep up are forced out of business. And the labour that is
displaced will, or at least should[4], be rapidly deployed to other
regions or sectors where it can be put to more productive use.
Yesterday’s rubbish?
From
the macroeconomic point of view it makes no sense at all to lock a
large proportion of the workforce into low-paid, low-productivity jobs.
If they were consistent, liberal economists and employers’ front
organisations should be making that point. But they are not. It could be
that they have suddenly abandoned liberal views as yesterday’s rubbish.
This is implausible, however. The argument still applies in other
areas; see for example the salutatory effects that such commentators
ascribe to the TTIP (Transtlantic Trade and Investment Partnership).
Rather
the discrepancy is presumably because the same effect is produced by
two different causes: trade or technological change, on the one hand,
which are seen as market outcomes, and the minimum wage, on the other, which is perceived as an market intervention.
This dichotomy is wrong, or at least oversimplistic, of course. Trade
and technology are also highly regulated, while many economists argue
that the minimum wage (at a reasonable level) is correcting a market
imperfection that gives undue power to employers. But even those who
believe in it should be aware of the inconsistency of using anecdotal
argument from individual companies as a stick with which to beat the
minimum wage.
It will be quite some
time before careful studies, with all the required controls, are made of
the employment impacts of the introduction of the statutory minimum
wage in Germany. Until they are done, expect a lot of heart-rending
anecdotal argument about job losses and bankruptcies. And when you hear
or read them, remember to confront those making such arguments with
Konrad Adenauer, or whoever it was who said: Was kümmert mich mein Geschwätz von gestern?
[1] In its „eight facts about the minimum wage“ the INSM states baldly (translation mine) „ The introduction of a minimum wage, whatever ist level, destroys all those jobs that no longer pay. And a job no longer pays when the employer gets less from it than he pays the worker. And so it is clear: the higher the minimum wgae, the greater the job losses.“
[2] In their annual report 2013/2014. It is worth emphasising that one of the „Five wise persons“, Peter Bofinger, dissented from the majority view on the minimum wage issue.
[3] The following may not apply to heads of individual companies, who can be very protectionist, but it usually does to those representing employer interests at national level.
[4] The word “should” here can be understood in the sense that redeployment will happen if appropriate measures are in place to maintain aggregate demand and smooth the adjustment process through active labour market policies. And of course provided the increase in the minimum wage is “reasonable” so that the employment reallocation system is not completely overwhelmed.
No comments:
Post a Comment